Google
Saturday 
November 9, 2024 

AmosWEB means Economics with a Touch of Whimsy!

AmosWEBWEB*pediaGLOSS*aramaECON*worldCLASS*portalQUIZ*tasticPED GuideXtra CrediteTutorA*PLS
ACCUMULATION: The process of acquiring an item and adding that item to others previously acquired. In an economic context this most often refers to the accumulation of capital, as in the phrase "capital accumulation." However, it is also used in the context of consumer durable goods, financial assets, money, wealth, and a host of other "stock" variables. When applied to capital, the process of accumulation occurs through investment.

Visit the GLOSS*arama


LONG-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY:

The total (or aggregate) real production of final goods and services available in the domestic economy at a range of price levels, during a period of time in which all prices, especially wages, are flexible, and have achieved their equilibrium levels. Long-run aggregate supply, commonly abbreviated LRAS, is one of two aggregate supply alternatives, distinguished by the degree of price flexibility. The other is short-run aggregate supply. Long-run aggregate supply is combined with aggregate demand, and often short-run aggregate supply, in the long-run aggregate market (or AS-AD) analysis used to analyze economic growth, business-cycle instability, unemployment, inflation, government stabilization policies, and related macroeconomic topics.
Long-run aggregate supply captures the lack of any relation between the economy's price level, measured by the GDP price deflator, and real production, measured by real GDP. Changes in the price level have no affect on the business sector's inclination to produce goods and services, in the long run. The level of production is that generated at full employment. Long-run price flexibility ensures that all markets, including resource markets are equilibrium, with no shortages or surpluses, which means that resources are fully employed.

The lack of any long-run relation between the price level and real production occurs due to the flexibility of prices and wages. In other words, prices adjust to achieve equilibrium and eliminate all market shortages and surpluses. This long-run aggregate supply relation is illustrated by a vertical long-run aggregate supply curve and can be better understood with a look at full employment and what happens when the price level rises or falls.

The Long-Run Aggregate Supply Curve

Long-Run Aggregate Supply Curve
Long-Run Aggregate Supply Curve
A typical long-run aggregate supply curve, labeled LRAS, is presented in this graph. Consider a few highlights.

  • First, the price level is measured on the vertical axis and real production is measured on the horizontal axis. The price level is usually measured by the GDP price deflator and real production is measured by real GDP.

  • Second, the long-run aggregate supply curve, labeled LRAS, is a vertical line. The aggregate real production offered for sale by the business sector is the same at higher price levels as it is at lower price levels. This constant level of aggregate real production is full-employment production.

  • Third, the price level and aggregate real production are the only two variables allowed to change in the construction of this curve. Everything else that could affect long-run aggregate supply is assumed to remain constant. Analogous to market supply, these other variables are ceteris paribus factors that fall under the heading of aggregate supply determinants.

  • Fourth, this long-run aggregate supply curve captures the relation between the price level and the flow of real production over a given time period. However, depending on the particular aggregate market analysis, the time period could be shorter (several months) or longer (several years). Of course, if the time period is too short, then the long-run aggregate supply curve might not be relevant.

Full Employment

The key characteristic of long-run aggregate supply is that full-employment production is maintained at ALL price levels. In the long run, when all prices and wages are flexible, all markets (financial, product, and especially resource) are in equilibrium, and the level of real production fully employs all available resources.

In principle, full employment is the condition that exists when all resources are engaged in production. In practice, however, this condition is not necessarily achieved. An economy ALWAYS has some unemployed resources, particularly frictionally and structurally unemployed resources.

  • Frictional unemployment results because resources are in the process of moving from one production activity to another, which does not happen instantaneously. The time needed to match up resources with production depends on the availability of information and the degree of geographic separation.

  • Structural unemployment results because resources, especially labor, are configured (trained) for a given technology but the economy demands goods and services using another technology, the productive capabilities of the resources do not match the requirements of the productive activities.
Both types of unemployment are a natural consequence of a healthy, efficient, and expanding economy. And unlike cyclical unemployment, neither can be eliminated totally. For this reason, the working definition of full employment used in macroeconomic analysis is based on market equilibrium. For all practical purposes full employment exists when the quantity of resources demanded is equal to the quantity of resources supplied. In other words, the number of available jobs is equal to the number of available workers. This does not require that ALL available jobs are filled. This does not require that ALL available workers have jobs. With the persistence of frictional and structural unemployment, neither of these can happen, EVER!

This market equilibrium notion of full employment means that resource prices reach equilibrium levels and do not change. There are NO shortages or surpluses in resource markets to prompt changes in resource prices. This lack of change in resource prices goes hand-in-hand with the notion of long-run price flexibility. In other words, resource prices have adjusted as much as needed to eliminated market imbalances. No imbalances persist and further price changes are not forthcoming. (Unless determinants shock the system and create new imbalances.)

The key implication is that the long-run aggregate supply is ALWAYS equal to full-employment production. It matters not what the price level is, it can be high, it can be low, full-employment production is maintained. In the long run, the economy never produces more or less than full-employment production. Producing more or less than full-employment production is a short-run phenomenon, not a long-run one.

Price Adjustments

The basic reason that long-run aggregate production is always full-employment production rests with the flexible prices. In particular, changes in the price level are met by equal changes in resource prices, especially wages. A lower price level might temporarily (in the short run) lead to a reduction in real production, below the full employment level, but in the long run, full employment production is maintained. A higher price level might temporarily (in the short run) lead to an increase in real production, above the full employment level, but in the long run, full employment production is also maintained.

Consider how and why long-run aggregate production and the employment of resources are not affected by changes in the economy's price level.

  • A Lower Price Level: First, consider a reduction in the price level. Individual firms react to lower prices according to the basic microeconomic principles of short-run production, including the law of supply and law of diminishing marginal returns. Each firm reduces production by employing fewer resources. When aggregated for the macroeconomy, total production declines and so too does the employment of resources, in the short run.

    However, the short run decline in production and resource employment occurs because ALL prices have not yet adjusted to equilibrium levels. In particular, resource markets are out of balance. The quantity of resources demanded is less than the quantity of resources supplied. This causes market surpluses and creates unemployment. While these resource market surpluses can persist in the short run due to inflexible prices, in the long run, flexible prices decline to eliminate the unemployment surpluses and achieve equilibrium.

    In particular, wages and other resource prices decline as much as the price level declines. If the price level falls by 10 percent, then wages and other resource prices ALSO decline by 10 percent. This equal proportional decline in prices ensures that the purchasing power of wages and other resource prices are the same after the price level decline as before the decline. This is important because real wages and real resource prices are the keys for determining the quantities of resources demanded and supplied. Employers hire workers based on real wages paid and workers take jobs based on real wages received.

    Because real resource prices are at their full-employment equilibrium levels BEFORE the price level decline and real resource prices are the same after the price level decline as they were before, then resource markets are at their full-employment equilibrium levels. The aggregate real production supplied AFTER the price level decline is exactly the same as BEFORE the price level decline. The decline in the price level has absolutely no affect on the aggregate real production.

  • A Higher Price Level: Now, consider what happens with a price level increase. Individual firms react to higher prices, once again, according to the basic microeconomic principles of short-run production, including the law of supply and law of diminishing marginal returns. Each firm increases production by employing more resources. When aggregated for the macroeconomy, total production increases and so too does the employment of resources, in the short run.

    However, the short run increase in production and resource employment occurs because ALL prices have not yet adjusted to equilibrium levels. Once again, resource markets are out of balance. The quantity of resources demanded is greater than the quantity of resources supplied. This causes market shortages that triggers overemployment of resources by reducing frictional and structural employment and temporarily enticing resources to increase productive efforts. While this overemployment and overproduction can persist in the short run due to inflexible prices, in the long run, flexible prices rise to eliminate the shortages and achieve equilibrium.

    In particular, wages and other resource prices rise as much as the price level increases. If the price level increases by 10 percent, then wages and other resource prices ALSO increase by 10 percent. This equal proportional increase in prices ensures that the purchasing power of wages and other resource prices are the same after the price level increases as before the increase. This is important because real wages and real resource prices are the keys for determining the quantities of resources demanded and supplied. Employers hire workers based on real wages paid and workers take jobs based on real wages received.

    Because real resource prices are at their full-employment equilibrium levels BEFORE the price level increase and real resource prices are the same after the price level increase as they were before, then resource markets are once again at full-employment equilibrium levels. The aggregate real production supplied AFTER the price level increase is exactly the same as BEFORE the price level increase. The increase in the price level has absolutely no affect on the aggregate real production.

<= LONG-RUN AGGREGATE MARKETLONG-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE =>


Recommended Citation:

LONG-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AmosWEB Encyclonomic WEB*pedia, http://www.AmosWEB.com, AmosWEB LLC, 2000-2024. [Accessed: November 9, 2024].


Check Out These Related Terms...

     | aggregate supply | short-run aggregate supply | long-run aggregate supply curve | aggregate supply determinants | aggregate demand | aggregate market analysis | aggregate market | long-run, macroeconomics | short-run, macroeconomics |


Or For A Little Background...

     | gross domestic product | price level | GDP price deflator | real gross domestic product | full employment | unemployment | frictional unemployment | structural unemployment | overemployment | macroeconomic markets | resource markets |


And For Further Study...

     | change in aggregate supply | change in real production | aggregate supply shifts | slope, long-run aggregate supply curve | slope, short-run aggregate supply curve | business cycles | circular flow | Keynesian economics | monetary economics | short-run aggregate supply and market supply |


Search Again?

Back to the WEB*pedia


APLS

ORANGE REBELOON
[What's This?]

Today, you are likely to spend a great deal of time at a going out of business sale seeking to buy either a wall poster commemorating the first day of spring or a lazy Susan for you dining room table. Be on the lookout for rusty deck screws.
Your Complete Scope

This isn't me! What am I?

The first paper notes printed in the United States were in denominations of 1 cent, 5 cents, 25 cents, and 50 cents.
"Laughter is the shortest distance between two people. "

-- Victor Borge, musician, humorist

IQ
Import Quota
A PEDestrian's Guide
Xtra Credit
Tell us what you think about AmosWEB. Like what you see? Have suggestions for improvements? Let us know. Click the User Feedback link.

User Feedback



| AmosWEB | WEB*pedia | GLOSS*arama | ECON*world | CLASS*portal | QUIZ*tastic | PED Guide | Xtra Credit | eTutor | A*PLS |
| About Us | Terms of Use | Privacy Statement |

Thanks for visiting AmosWEB
Copyright ©2000-2024 AmosWEB*LLC
Send comments or questions to: WebMaster