Google
Monday 
May 21, 2018 

AmosWEB means Economics with a Touch of Whimsy!

AmosWEBWEB*pediaGLOSS*aramaECON*worldCLASS*portalQUIZ*tasticPED GuideXtra CrediteTutorA*PLS
UNEMPLOYMENT: The general condition in which resources are willing and able to produce goods and services but are not engaged in productive activities. While unemployment is most commonly thought of in terms of labor, any of the other factors of production (capital, land, and entrepreneurship) can be unemployed as well. The analysis of unemployment, especially labor unemployment, goes hand-in-hand with the study of macroeconomics that emerged from the Great Depression of the 1930s.

Visit the GLOSS*arama


KEYNESIAN EQUILIBRIUM:

The state of macroeconomic equilibrium identified by the Keynesian model when the opposing forces of aggregate expenditures equal aggregate production achieve a balance with no inherent tendency for change. Once achieved, a Keynesian equilibrium persists unless or until it is disrupted by an outside force, especially changes in autonomous expenditures.
Macroeconomic equilibrium is achieved in the Keynesian model by a balance of aggregate production and aggregate expenditures. As with other economic models, equilibrium in the Keynesian model is a state that exists when two opposing forces exactly offset one another such that nothing changes until or unless an outside force intervenes.

Aggregate Forces

The two opposing forces that achieve equilibrium in the Keynesian model of macroeconomics are aggregate production and aggregate expenditures.
  • Aggregate Production: The first half of the balance is aggregate production, the total quantity of final goods and services produced in the economy. This total or aggregate production is most commonly measured by gross domestic product.

  • Aggregate Expenditures: The other half of the equilibrium balance is aggregate expenditures, the combined expenditures on final goods and services undertaken by the four macroeconomic sectors (household, business, government, and foreign). The four aggregate expenditures (and their common abbreviation) are: consumption expenditures (C), investment expenditures (I), government purchases (G), and net exports (X - M). Aggregate expenditures are commonly represented by an simple equation:
    AE=C+I+G+(X-M)
A couple of points about Keynesian equilibrium are worth a note:
  • First, the adjustment mechanism that achieves and maintains equilibrium is aggregate production. If aggregate expenditures are not equal to aggregate production, then aggregate production changes to restore balance.

  • Second, Keynesian equilibrium is ONLY a balance between aggregate expenditures and aggregate production. Other aggregate markets, especially resource markets, need not be in equilibrium. Shortages and surpluses can exist and persist in resource markets. In other words, full employment is NOT automatically achieved with Keynesian equilibrium.

Setting the Keynesian Stage

Keynesian Cross
Keynesian Cross


Equilibrium
Keynesian Cross

Disequilibrium
Disequilibrium

The best way to illustrate Keynesian equilibrium is with the Keynesian cross intersection between the aggregate expenditures line (AE) and the 45-degree (Y = AE) line.

Consider the exhibit to the right. This illustrates the standard framework for the Keynesian model, with aggregate production measured on the horizontal axis and aggregate expenditures measured on the vertical axis.

  • One of two items needed to identify equilibrium is the 45-degree guideline. This can be displayed by clicking the [45-Degree Line] button. The resulting line is labeled Y = AE.

  • The other item needed is the aggregate expenditures line. This can be displayed by clicking the [Aggregate Expenditures Line] button. The resulting line is labeled AE.

An Intersecting Equilibrium

With both lines in place, the next step is to identify equilibrium, which can be accomplished using the exhibit to the right. Equilibrium in the Keynesian model is achieved at the intersection of the 45-degree line and the aggregate expenditures line. Click the [Equilibrium] button to identify this point and corresponding aggregate production.
  • Equilibrium is achieved with $12 trillion of aggregate production. At this level, aggregate expenditures are also $12 trillion.

  • Only at $12 trillion are aggregate expenditures equal to aggregate production. At every other production level, aggregate expenditures are either greater than or less than aggregate production.

  • At this $12 trillion level, there are no economy-wide surpluses or shortages because buyers buy all they want and sellers sell all they have.

  • The lack of surpluses and shortages means equilibrium. Neither buyers nor sellers are dissatisfied with this condition, and thus have no reason to alter the production level.

  • A key indicator of this equilibrium is business inventories -- stockpiles of raw materials and finished goods. The business sector has no unexpected, or unplanned, changes in inventories.

Out of Balance

Once the Keynesian model achieves equilibrium it remains in equilibrium. But what happens if the level of aggregate production does not achieve equilibrium? What if aggregate production is less than or greater than that needed for equilibrium? Fortunately, the Keynesian model has a stable equilibrium. That is, should the model not be in equilibrium it moves toward equilibrium.

Disequilibrium in the Keynesian model results when aggregate expenditures are not equal to aggregate production. More specifically, this is an aggregate production level that does not coincide with the intersection of the aggregate expenditures line and the 45-degree line.

A graphical analysis of disequilibrium is in order. The exhibit to the right displays equilibrium in the Keynesian model. Aggregate production is $12 trillion at the intersection of the aggregate expenditures line and the 45-degree line. If aggregate production is greater than or less than $12 trillion, we have disequilibrium. Let's consider each alternative.

  • Greater Than $12 Trillion: Suppose aggregate production is $18 trillion. Click the [$18 Trillion] button to highlight this alternative. At $18 trillion, the aggregate expenditures line lies beneath the 45-degree line and aggregate expenditures are $16.5 trillion, less than aggregate production.

    The difference between aggregate expenditures and aggregate production means that economy-wide production surpluses exist. Economy-wide surpluses result in unplanned increases in inventories because the business sector sells less output than current production. The $1.5 trillion vertical distance between the aggregate expenditures line and the 45-degree line indicates the increase in business inventories.

    The build-up of inventories motivates the business sector to reduce aggregate production. The decrease in aggregate production then moves the economy to the $12 trillion equilibrium level. In the course of this adjustment, aggregate expenditures decline from $16.5 trillion to $12 trillion.


  • Less Than $12 Trillion: Now suppose aggregate production is $6 trillion. Click the [$6 Trillion] button to highlight this alternative. At $6 trillion, the aggregate expenditures line lies above the 45-degree line and aggregate expenditures are $7.5 trillion, greater than aggregate production.

    The difference between aggregate expenditures and aggregate production means that economy-wide production shortages exist. Economy-wide shortages result in unplanned decreases in inventories because the business sector sells more output than current production. The $1.5 trillion vertical distance between the aggregate expenditures line and the 45-degree line indicates the decrease in business inventories.

    The reduction of inventories motivates the business sector to increase aggregate production. The increase in aggregate production then moves the economy to the $12 trillion equilibrium level. In the course of this adjustment, aggregate expenditures rise from $7.5 trillion to $12 trillion.

Changes in business inventories play a key role in the adjustment to equilibrium by signalling the business sector to increase or decrease aggregate production. For this reason, those who track the ups and downs of business cycles tend to keep a close eye on business inventories. A sudden and unexpected drop is a likely sign of an expansion of the economy. A sudden and unexpected rise is a likely sign of a contraction.

<= KEYNESIAN ECONOMICSKEYNESIAN MODEL =>


Recommended Citation:

KEYNESIAN EQUILIBRIUM, AmosWEB Encyclonomic WEB*pedia, http://www.AmosWEB.com, AmosWEB LLC, 2000-2018. [Accessed: May 21, 2018].


Check Out These Related Terms...

     | Keynesian model | two-sector Keynesian model | three-sector Keynesian model | four-sector Keynesian model | Keynesian disequilibrium | recessionary gap, Keynesian model | inflationary gap, Keynesian model | injections-leakages model | multiplier | fiscal policy |


Or For A Little Background...

     | equilibrium | market equilibrium | Keynesian economics | Keynesian cross | aggregate expenditures | aggregate expenditures line | 45-degree line | gross domestic product | macroeconomic sectors | macroeconomic markets |


And For Further Study...

     | change in private inventories | expansionary fiscal policy | contractionary fiscal policy | automatic stabilizers | injections | leakages | Keynesian cross and aggregate market | expenditures multiplier | accelerator principle | paradox of thrift | aggregate market analysis | business cycles |


Search Again?

Back to the WEB*pedia


APLS

BEIGE MUNDORTLE
[What's This?]

Today, you are likely to spend a great deal of time going from convenience store to convenience store looking to buy either a birthday gift for your father that doesn't look like every other birthday gift for your father or a green fountain pen. Be on the lookout for letters from the Internal Revenue Service.
Your Complete Scope

This isn't me! What am I?

Junk bonds are so called because they have a better than 50% chance of default, carrying a Standard & Poor's rating of CC or lower.
"Many people think that if they were only in some other place, or had some other job, they would be happy. Well, that is doubtful. So get as much happiness out of what you are doing as you can and don't put off being happy until some future date. "

-- Dale Carnegie

LWP
Leave With Pay
A PEDestrian's Guide
Xtra Credit
Tell us what you think about AmosWEB. Like what you see? Have suggestions for improvements? Let us know. Click the User Feedback link.

User Feedback



| AmosWEB | WEB*pedia | GLOSS*arama | ECON*world | CLASS*portal | QUIZ*tastic | PED Guide | Xtra Credit | eTutor | A*PLS |
| About Us | Terms of Use | Privacy Statement |

Thanks for visiting AmosWEB
Copyright ©2000-2018 AmosWEB*LLC
Send comments or questions to: WebMaster